четверг, 15 марта 2012 г.

NKorean wage demands could jeopardize factories

A joint project between the Koreas to build an industrial park in the North was hailed as a symbol of detente, but it has now become another point of friction between the two countries.

Drawn by cheap North Korean labor, more than 100 South Korean companies have set up factories at Kaesong. The North says the labor is too cheap, a position that some South Korean analysts said Wednesday could threaten the existence of the complex itself.

North Korean workers in the complex just north of the heavily armed border are paid about $70 a month on average _ about half that of Chinese laborers at South Korean factories in China, according to the South Korean …

Illinois Criterium set for tour de force

American Greg LeMond's victory in the Tour de France will havean impact on Sunday's Sun-Times Illinois Criterium Championships,according to director Ken Carl.

The 16-race program in Downers Grove has drawn more than 600riders. When the Crit made its debut fives years ago, there were 172riders. Last year, 550 cyclists competed. Race day registrationwill start at 8 a.m.

"We're expecting a strong increase in participants due to thepopularity of cycling and LeMond's success," Carl said. "There's beena big effect from that."

This year's Illinois Criterium field will not only be bigger,it will be much faster. Professionals will ride for the first timein …

Scientist pleads guilty to attempted espionage

WASHINGTON (AP) — An accomplished former government space scientist admitted in court Wednesday to trying to sell classified information to Israel, but federal agents say they believe they stopped him from actually passing any secrets. Not that they can know for sure.

The investigators say the undercover sting operation that caught Stewart David Nozette might never have been launched if he hadn't been cheating on his taxes. But it has ended with Nozette facing 13 years in prison.

Nozette pleaded guilty to one count of attempted espionage, admitting he tried to provide Israel with top secret information about satellites, early warning systems, ways of retaliating against …

Injured Yao Ming enjoying team owner role in China

Sidelined by a foot injury, Houston Rockets star Yao Ming says he's finding a new kind of satisfaction as owner of his former Chinese team, the Shanghai Sharks.

Yao bought out the financially troubled team's former owners in July for an undisclosed sum in a bid to revive its fortunes.

The club is in fourth in the 17-team Chinese league, two points out of first place.

"I bought the Sharks to give them a boost and do something on behalf of Chinese basketball," Yao said in an interview with the official Xinhua News Agency appearing in newspapers Thursday.

"To be honest, they've played well this season, beyond my …

среда, 14 марта 2012 г.

On the alert for converts // Spirit-filled Christians' goal: billions

INDIANAPOLIS Spirit-filled, tongue-speaking Christians are on aroll.

They now represent one of every five Christians across theglobe, hoping to expand their numbers into the billions by the turnof the century.

While those figures enlivened the hearts of some 30,000Pentecostals and charismatics gathered here last week, the throng wasdead serious about getting on with their task.

The goal: Convert at least half the world's 5.3 billion peopleto Christianity by 2000 and the balance in due time.

Atheists and those of no faith aren't the only objective.Moslems, Hindus, Buddhists and Jews also are targets.

The thousands descended on the …

Building Public Trust: The Future of Corporate Reporting

by Samuel A. DiPiazza Jr., CEO of PricewaterhouseCoopers, and Robert G. Eccles, president of Advisory Capital Partners Published by John Wiley & Sons Inc. 188 pages $24.95

In the wake of the Enron bankruptcy, public trust in those responsible for reporting corporate performance information has been shaken to its foundation. Investors and other …

Credit crunch enters the dictionary

The terms credit crunch, carbon footprint and wardrobe malfunction have become such staples that they have won entry into the new version of The Chambers Dictionary, the publisher announced Thursday.

The new words reflect "today's preoccupations" with the environment, the faltering economy and _ of course _ celebrity gossip, the dictionary's Edinburgh, Scotland-based publisher said.

Chambers is the second British dictionary to announce inclusion in its pages of credit crunch _ "a sudden and drastic reduction in the availability of credit" _ indicating how deeply Britons are feeling the effects of the economic turmoil on their …

Beavers haven't played a total game

DAILY MAIL SPORTS EDITOR

Fred Simon's Christmas wish list consists of two items, whicharen't his front teeth.

The Bluefield High School football coach simply wants his offenseto play well and his defense to shine - on the same night, in thesame game.

Oh, and you can throw special teams in there too.

Simon said the Beavers have yet to put together a completeperformance this season, one in which the offense excels, thedefense is rock solid and the special teams are truly special.

Bluefield has teased its coach with flashes of brilliance in allof those areas this season. But it seems like when the Beavers arepounding opposing offenses, their defense …

House approves bill that addresses epidemic for Blacks

The Illinois General Assembly unanimously passed a bill Thursday that will coordinate the efforts of several state agencies in addressing the AIDS crisis in the African American community.

House Bill 2578, also known as the African American HIV/AIDS Response Act, was introduced in February by Rep. Connie Howard (D-32nd).

Howard told the Chicago Defender the state now recognizes the "extreme emergency" existing in our community.

The bill provides for state agencies to coordinate with local health organizations to conduct HIV/AIDS testing and counseling; for Chicago State University's Research Department to study the connection between incarceration and HIV infection; …

Redd, Villanueva lift Bucks over Raptors

Michael Redd had a season-high 35 points and Charlie Villanueva scored 13 of his 25 in the fourth quarter, leading Milwaukee to its first win without Andrew Bogut in 21 months, 107-97 over the Toronto Raptors on Monday night.

Milwaukee, which finished the game on a 13-0 run, lost its previous nine games _ including four this season _ without Bogut, the former No. 1 pick who missed his second straight game Monday with back spasms.

But instead of relying on their defense, which has been much better of late, the Bucks simply outscored the Raptors down the stretch, getting 11 points each from Charlie Bell and Ramon Sessions and sending one of the NBA's most …

Contras refuse to give up arms

MANAGUA Leaders of Nicaragua's U.S.-backed contras rejected apeace proposal offered Sunday by the Sandinista government, saying itwould require contra forces to surrender their arms before movinginto cease-fire zones.

Contra leaders called the proposal a setback that raises doubtsover whether the war can be ended.

"There are new elements in the proposal that didn't existbefore," contra leader Pedro Joaquin Chamorro said. "Some are verydangerous steps that could potentially affect this process and beginthe war once again."

The contras said the proposal requires the disarmament of allrebel forces before they gather into seven cease-fire zones for a60-day …

Phoenix Takes WNBA Title With 108-92 Win

AUBURN HILLS, Mich. - The tattoo on Cappie Pondexter's arm was inked when she was still in high school. It features the WNBA logo, and reads "The Future."

That future is now for Pondexter and the Phoenix Mercury, who beat the Detroit Shock 108-92 on Sunday and wrapped up their first league title in the deciding Game 5 of the championship series.

A fast start helped Phoenix become the first team in the WNBA's 11-year history to claim the title on the road. Pondexter, in her second year in the league, scored 26 points and was chosen as the series MVP.

"It's been a long time coming," said Pondexter, who didn't win an NCAA championship while at Rutgers. "It's …

Lieberman: We can break barriers

LOS ANGELES Joseph Lieberman, vowing to "break down barriers,"made history Wednesday night as he became the first Jewish nominee ona major party's ticket.

"Is America a great country or what?" asked the Democratic vicepresidential nominee.

The Connecticut senator drew a parallel between himself and JohnF. Kennedy, who 40 years ago broke down another barrier when hebecame the first Roman Catholic elected to the presidency.

"Forty years ago we came to this city and crossed a new frontier,"Lieberman said. ". . . I believe that the next frontier isn't just infront of us, but inside of us-to overcome the differences that arestill between us, to break down the barriers that remain; and to helpevery American claim the limitless opportunities of our own lives."

Lieberman paid tribute to Democratic presidential candidate AlGore for defying ancient prejudices in choosing him for the ticket.He also acknowledged their occasional policy differences and hailedhim as a man of faith.

"I've known Al Gore for 15 years," he said. "I know his record andI know his heart. I know him as a public servant and I know what itis like to sit with him around the dining room table. We havediscussed, sometimes even debated, policy issues. And we have sharedprivate moments of prayer."

Drawing a contrast with the Republicans, Lieberman said, "I'm gladthe GOP has changed their rhetoric, but I wish they would changetheir policies."

Lieberman asserted that Texas Gov. George W. Bush's proposals toimprove the nation's schools were inadequate.

"It's a good thing that our opponent talks about education.Schools need to be held to the highest standards of performance andaccountability," he said. "But I'm sad to say their plan does notprovide the resources our schools need to meet those high standards.I've read their plan. To me, it seems like their idea of schoolmodernization means buying a new calendar for every building."

Gore's running mate spoke of his family's influence in shaping hisvalues, recalling that his father was raised in an orphanage and wenton to drive a bakery truck and own a store in Stamford, Conn.

"Sometimes I try to see this world as my dad saw it from hisbakery truck. About this time, he'd be getting ready for the all-night run. I know that somewhere in America right now, there isanother father loading a bakery truck, or a young man programming acomputer, or a parent dreaming of a better future for their daughteror their son. If we keep the faith, then 40 years from now, one oftheir children will stand before a gathering like this, with a chanceto serve and lead the country that we love."

Earlier in the day, Gore arrived at Burbank Airport and wasgreeted by Lieberman. The vice presidential nominee urged the crowdto "help me win one for the Tipper," a reference to Mrs. Gore and aplay on Ronald Reagan's famous line to "win one for the Gipper."

For the third day, there were angry confrontations outside theconvention hall between demonstrators and Los Angeles police.

In contrast with the Philadelphia convention, where the Bushcampaign allowed few GOP senators and congressmen to have speakingroles, Democratic legislators have been prominently showcased.

House Minority Leader Richard Gephardt, with whom Gore has haddifferences, told the party faithful Wednesday night: "Al Gore is agood man. He is a decent, caring man. He loves his family. He lovesthis country. He could be the best president this country will everhave."

Gore wraps up the four-day convention tonight in a speech thatspokesman Doug Hattaway promised to "go beyond the surface." Gore waspolishing the final draft today, and it's not clear yet if he will beas blunt in his assessment of rival Bush as the Texas governor was ofGore in his acceptance speech in Philadelphia.

"He's going to talk about the era of prosperity as a uniqueopportunity that we need to use wisely," Hattaway said.

Poland late president's brother thanks supporters

The twin brother of Poland's late president Lech Kaczynski has made his first appearance since announcing he would run for office in his brother's place, saying he wants a powerful and just Poland.

Jaroslaw Kaczynski, appeared briefly Thursday at his Law and Justice party headquarters to thank supporters for some 1.6 million signatures of support for him in the presidential race.

A minimum of 100,000 signatures is required of registered candidates.

Poland called early elections June 20 after the incumbent was killed April 10 in a plane crash in Russia.

Kaczynski, a former prime minister, is trailing in the polls behind acting president, Parliament Speaker Bronislaw Komorowski.

вторник, 13 марта 2012 г.

Caption Only [Color Photo: Claudio Scaccini, AP / BLOODY THURSDAY:...]

Caption text only.

Bangladesh: Government Intensifies Trade with Australia

Bangladesh held a trade fair in Sydney, Australia for the first time in April. 53 participants concluded contracts with Australian firms centering on knitted wear, hand woven fabrics, and footwear, etc. According to the Export Promotion Bureau, the trade balance shows a deficit for Bangladesh as imports from Australia exceed Bangladesh's exports to Australia. Imports amounted to US$220 million against the estimation, of US$36 million for 2002-2003. In order to expand trade between the two countries, the Australia-Bangladesh Chamber of Commerce and Industry was established in January 2004. The statistics of EPB show that exports to Australia decreased 17% for 20032004 as a result of exporters' reluctant deals with deregulation or quota-free business. Bangladeshi exports to Australia amounted to US$30.586 million for 2003-04. The government plans to intensify export promotion by demonstrating their textile products at international trade fairs.

Stephen Hawking suggests 'theory of everything'

"The Grand Design" (Random House, $28), by Stephen Hawking and Leonard Mlodinow: Cosmologists, the people who study the entire cosmos, will want to read British physicist and mathematician Stephen Hawking's new book.

"The Grand Design" may sharpen appetites for answers to questions like "Why is there something rather than nothing?" and "Why do we exist?" — questions that have troubled thinking people at least as far back as the ancient Greeks.

Hawking likes the tale of the old lady who accused a lecturing cosmologist of talking nonsense: She knew for a fact that the whole universe lies on a flat plate, borne on the back of an enormous turtle.

"What does the turtle stand on?" the lecturer asked.

"Another turtle," she replied. "It's turtles all the way down."

For some readers, the answer from Hawking, known for his work on black holes and author of the best-selling "A Brief History of Time," and physicist Leonard Mlodinow, may not be much more satisfying.

The "grand design," says Hawking, is to be found in M-theory, an idea launched in the mid-1990s.

Annoyingly, there's no agreement on what the "M'' stands for. The authors suggest "master," ''miracle" or "mystery." Others have also been proposed, but none of these names offers the layman much help in answering the basic questions.

"According to M-theory, ours is not the only universe. Instead, M-theory predicts that a great many universes were created out of nothing. Their creation does not require the intervention of some supernatural being or god," the book says. "Rather, these multiple universes arise naturally from physical law."

This idea may trouble anyone who was fair at high school math but didn't major in the subject in college.

"M-theory has solutions," the book says later, "that allow for many different internal spaces, perhaps as many as 10 (followed by 500 zeros), which means it allows for 10 (followed by 500 zeros) different universes, each with its own laws."

A layman may wonder if one of those multitudinous laws might furnish a simple explanation of why something exists instead of nothing — and also wonder if there might be no such law in any of the possible universes.

Hawking writes that M-theory is a unified "theory of everything" that Albert Einstein was looking for but never found.

"If the theory is confirmed by observation, it will be the successful conclusion of a search going back more than 3,000 years. We will have found the grand design."

___

Online:

http://www.hawking.org.uk/

Ronaldo does not plan return to Europe

Ronaldo is content finishing his career in Brazil, and the prolific striker does not plan a return to Europe.

"I think that phase of my career and my life has concluded," the Brazilian said in an interview with the Gazzetta dello Sport on Wednesday. "It was a great adventure, but logic and (my) heart tell me it's over.

"I'm going to conclude my career in Brazil and the most natural thing will be to do it with Corinthians."

The 32-year-old Ronaldo signed a one-year contract with Corinthians late last year and has played four games for the Brazilian club. He is working his way back into form after a third knee operation.

Ronaldo began his European career with PSV Eindhoven in 1994 and went on to play for continental powerhouses FC Barcelona, Inter Milan, Real Madrid and AC Milan.

His last European match came with AC Milan in February of last year, when he ruptured a tendon in his left knee in a Serie A game with Livorno. He was released by Milan at the end of the season.

As the all-time leading World Cup scorer with 15 goals, Ronaldo is still hoping for a return to Brazil's squad in time for next year's tournament in South Africa.

"First I've got to score 30 goals (with Corinthians), then we'll discuss it with (coach) Dunga," Ronaldo said. "Playing in the World Cup was always my biggest joy."

Ex-bodyguard who admitted role in 1994 attack on Olympic skater Nancy Kerrigan dies at 40

Brian Sean Griffith, a former bodyguard to figure skater Tonya Harding who admitted a role in the attack on her rival Nancy Kerrigan during Olympics tryouts, has died. He was 40.

Griffith died Wednesday of what his doctor reported as natural causes, according to the Washington County medical examiner's office. The specific cause of death is expected to be listed when the doctor files a death certificate, which could take two weeks, the medical examiner's office said.

Formerly Shawn Eckardt, Griffith had changed his name since the attack in an attempt to put it behind him.

Griffith, of Beaverton, was Harding's bodyguard when the Portland-born skater competed for a spot on the U.S. Olympic figure skating team in 1994.

That January, an assailant clubbed Kerrigan in the knee, forcing her out of the competition. The International Committee of the U.S. Figure Skating Association granted Kerrigan a spot anyway, and she recovered in time to win a silver medal at the Olympics.

Days after the attack, Griffith confessed, detailing a plan that he and Harding's ex-husband, Jeff Gillooly, had hatched. The investigation also eventually netted convictions of Shane Stant, the actual attacker, and Stant's uncle, Derrick Smith, who drove the getaway car.

Griffith was sentenced to 18 months in prison for racketeering but was released four months early, in September 1995.

He started a computer business, Applied Information Systems Inc., in 2001, but state records show it was dissolved in 2005. He was also sentenced to three years' probation for misdemeanor assault in 2001.

Family members refused Friday to comment on Griffith's life before or since the infamous attack.

"Shawn Eckardt died a long time ago," his brother, Mike Skinner, told The Oregonian. "There is no other person than Brian Griffith."

Harding has always said she did not know of the plan. She pleaded guilty to conspiracy to hinder an investigation and was banned from U.S. Figure Skating Association competitions.

PLUS BUSINESS

Leeson's Release Sought Nicholas Leeson's attorneys filed a 160-page brief with Germanauthorities in their attempt to prevent the extradition to Singaporeof the young trader accused of breaking Barings Bank. The legalpapers, filed with German authorities on the very last daypermissible, demanded Leeson's immediate and unconditional release,said prosecutor Hans-Hermann Eckert. Leeson, 28, is charged withforgery and fraud in Singapore, where he was based when his tradingon Asian futures markets were blamed for bringing down Britain'stradition-rich Barings Bank. Leeson has been in a Frankfurt jailsince he was arrested in Germany on March 2 on his way home toBritain. Home Resales Jump 5% in July Sales of previously owned homes shot up 5 percent in July to thehighest level in more than a year as low mortgage rates kept housingcosts within reach of many buyers. The National Association ofRealtors said that sales of existing single-family homes totaled aseasonally adjusted annual rate of 3.99 million, up from 3.80 millionin June and the highest since a 4.01 million rate in June, 1994. Itwas the third straight monthly advance. Sales rose in every regionexcept for the Midwest, where they fell 1 percent. The median pricein the Midwest was $96,500. First USA Acquiring 2 Firms First USA Inc. said it will acquire the nation's two largestindependent direct marketing credit card processors in separate stockand cash deals for undisclosed terms. Dallas-based First USA, one ofthe nation's largest providers of Visa and MasterCard services, saidit will offer its stock to acquire Litle & Co., of Salem, N.H., andpay cash for DMGT Corp., of Nashua, N.H. Litle and DMGT processed$10.2 billion in Visa; MasterCard transactions in the fiscal yearended June 30. Of that, about 58 percent was processed through FirstUSA in connection with its existing relationship with Litle. GM Seeks European Growth General Motors Corp. said it hopes to continue gaining market sharein Europe in the second half of 1995 after posting strong growth inthe first six months. "We've had a very strong first half in termsof market share," GM International President Louis Hughes said. TheU.S. automaker's European unit last month said its western Europeanmarket share rose to 12.8 percent in the first six months of thisyear, up from 12.5 percent in the same 1994 period. Hughes saidgrowth in the overall European auto market was mixed so far thisyear. Tokyo Stocks Drop Stocks slipped in Tokyo, with the Nikkei average falling 151.31points to 17,770.68. Outlook Raises Corn Prices Corn futures prices rose modestly today on the Chicago Board ofTrade amid talk of crop disease and lower production prospects. Oatfutures also rose while wheat and soybeans ended mixed. Reports ofspreading gray leaf spot fungus in southern Iowa underpinned cornprices, although analysts said the damage probably will be limited.Another type of fungus, aflatoxin, has been reported in southern cornstates, which include Georgia, Kentucky and North Carolina. "Theymay not be the biggest corn producers compared to the Midwesternstates, but you need those states to come through with good yields toget the high national yields the Agriculture Department is lookingfor," said grain analyst Jack Scoville of the Linn Group in Chicago.He said crop conditions are worse than previously thought in some ofthe historically top-producing areas of Iowa and Minnesota. "Ifthey're not going to come through with the crop yields, then there'sa chance the USDA crop production estimates were seriouslyoverstated," Scoville said. Earlier this month, the USDA predicted acorn crop of 8.12 billion bushels. The agency will revise its cropforecasts Sept. 12. Wheat for September delivery slipped 1/4 centto $4.40 3/4 a bushel; September corn rose 2 1/2 cents to $2.88 3/4 abushel; September oats climbed 4 1/2 cents to $1.69 a bushel;September soybeans slipped 1/4 cent to $5.96 3/4 a bushel.

Rockets' brass, fans pin blame on Olajuwon

The Houston Rockets are the first winning team not to make theplayoffs since the league increased the postseason field to 16 teamsin 1983.

Rockets fans and management generally think center HakeemOlajuwon is as much to blame as anybody, and management would like totrade him for the rights to Louisiana State center Shaquille O'Nealor for Philadelphia 76ers bad boy Charles Barkley.

The Rockets were 37-30 when Olajuwon, who already had missedeight games with injuries, said he had a hamstring injury and refusedto play despite medical clearance. The Rockets said Olajuwon wasfeigning the injury because he was unhappy with the progress of hiscontract talks.

The Rockets went 0-5 while Olajuwon sat out and never recovered.They needed to win only one of their last three games, but they lostthem all.

The only significant veterans dropped from the final playoffrosters submitted to the league Monday were San Antonio Spurs guardWillie Anderson and Phoenix Suns guard Negele Knight.

Suns forward Tom Chambers was left on roster despite beinginjured. So was Spurs center David Robinson, whose hand is expectedto be healed if the Spurs make it into the later rounds.

Detroit Pistons coach Chuck Daly said the only problem beingnamed the Olympic coach caused him this season was the fact he hadthree players - Isiah Thomas, Dennis Rodman and Joe Dumars - selectedby the Olympic committee.

"Somehow, they thought I had a vote on the selection committee,but I didn't," Daly said. "In fact, one of the stipulations I madewhen I accepted the post was that I would not have a vote."

Some members of the USA Basketball Olympic selection committeewould like to see two more NBA players added to the team in the nexttwo weeks.

"I just don't see any college players out there better than NBAplayers we could put on the team," one committee member said.

The trials and tribulations of Barkley in Philadelphia thisseason is simply another warning to owners not to keep players whodon't want to play for them. They will end up being more harmfulthan helpful.

понедельник, 12 марта 2012 г.

North Korea Says Nuclear Test Successful

SEOUL, South Korea - North Korea said Monday it has performed its first-ever nuclear weapons test. The country's official Korean Central News Agency said the test was performed successfully and there was no radioactive leakage from the site.

"The nuclear test is a historic event that brought happiness to the our military and people," KCNA said.

South Korea's Yonhap news agency said the test was conducted at 10:36 a.m. (9:36 p.m. EDT Sunday) in Hwaderi near Kilju city, citing defense officials.

BOJ Leaves Interest Rate Unchanged

TOKYO - The Bank of Japan held its benchmark interest rate steady at 0.5 percent at a two-day policy meeting that ended Tuesday after lifting it a quarter point last month.

Government data released earlier this month showed that consumer prices were flat for the first time in eight months in January, fueling speculation that the central bank would hold off for quite awhile before raising interest rates again.

Recent market volatility has also clouded the outlook for the Japanese economy.

Some analysts speculate the BOJ will wait until midyear parliamentary elections in Japan before deciding to raise rates again.

South Side Couple Will Keep Trying to Make a Difference Series: NEIGHBORHOOD HEROES

A week with Otis Monroe and Virginia Hardrict is like a crashcourse in the problems of urban America.

The husband-and-wife community activists might be cajoling abank to open a branch in a South Side neighborhood on one day. Thenext, they'll be out persuading gangbangers to trade in theirbaseball caps for mortarboards.

By the end of the week, they could be on a street corner passingout condoms along with warnings about risky sex, or telling a younggirl that an education, more than a baby, will bolster herself-esteem.

In an area that includes the West Lawn, Gresham, Englewood,Roseland and South Shore neighborhoods, they do everything fromhelping find funds for other small community groups to operating asafe house in Englewood for repentent gang members.

It's a job that comes with long hours, little thanks and lots ofnaysayers.

"And not much money," Hardrict said, laughing. "I didn't getinto this because of the money. I have a genuine interest in thisarea. My grandmother used to say, `Nothing beats failure like atry.' And we are going to try until we know for ourselves thatnothing is going to happen."

The couple also run the Englewood Streets Alternative Project,funded through the Chicago Community Trust, which seeks to get gangmembers off the streets and into jobs or anti-gang work. During thesummer, the project ran a safe house in Englewood where workers andgang members could talk.

Monroe and Hardrict also direct the Monroe Foundation from anoffice in their Gresham neighborhood home. The foundation givesassistance and modest grants to community organizations.

They run a program called Project Loan, which seeks to bring abank or a credit union to the Auburn-Gresham area. Most of theirwork is done quietly.

"We're just seeing what kind of options we can create," Monroesaid. "Everything doesn't always have to be done by marching up anddown someplace or yelling and screaming."

They counsel teenagers. "For a lot of them, their self-esteemis dragging on the ground," Hardrict said of the girls she helps."Some of them need to know that there is more to being a black womanthan having a baby . . . that you have to love yourself before anyonecan love you."

Monroe and Hardrict married in 1990 after doing community worktogether in West Englewood.

The Monroe foundation was born a year later, Hardrict said.

"One day we were sitting up talking about dreams and he said,`You know what my one big dream is? A foundation,' " she said. "Onour first anniversary, I set up a meeting with several bankpresidents and said, `Here's your anniversary present. You wanted afoundation? Here's some people to back it.' "

"Virgina is the rock when I'm feeling down," Monroe said."People come around and try to discredit us and tell us we don't havea purpose, but she is the rock and very much is the strength thatkeeps this whole thing tied together."

SKorea hosts ASEAN leaders amid NKorea tensions

South Korea and Thailand criticized North Korea on Sunday, saying the country's nuclear test threatens world peace and stability and harms efforts to prevent atomic proliferation.

The two nations' leaders discussed Pyongyang's latest nuclear blast on the sidelines of a summit between South Korea and Southeast Asian countries being held amid heavy security.

The event was planned months ago, but North Korea's underground nuclear test and a series of short-range missile launches last week threatens to steal the limelight from economic matters, the main focus of the agenda.

South Korean President Lee Myung-bak and Thai Prime Minister Abhisit Vejjajiva agreed that the test goes against international efforts to prevent nuclear proliferation and "undermines peace and stability not only in East Asia but also in the whole world," Lee Dong-kwan, the South Korean president's chief spokesman, told reporters.

They also agreed to exert diplomatic pressure to assure North Korea complies with U.N. Security Council resolutions and "promptly returns to six-party talks" aimed at ridding it of nuclear weapons.

The summit venue of Seogwipo _ on the island of Jeju off the southern coast _ is the South Korean city farthest away from the North. Still, the nervous South Korean government is taking no chances, positioning a surface-to-air missile outside the venue aimed toward the north.

Some 5,000 police officers, including approximately 200 commandos, and special vehicles that can analyze sarin gas and other chemicals have been deployed nearby, security authorities said in a press release. Marines, special forces and air patrols also kept watch on the island.

Leaders of the 10 members of the Association of Southeast Asian Nations began arriving for the two-day summit, which officially begins Monday and commemorates 20 years of relations between South Korea and the bloc. South Korea's president planned to use Sunday for individual meetings with ASEAN leaders.

But concerns about North Korea's most recent bout of saber-rattling loomed. South Korean officials said Saturday that spy satellites had spotted signs that the North may be preparing to transport a long-range missile to a launch site.

The North has attacked South Korean targets before, bombing a Korea Air jet in 1987 and trying to kill then-President Chun Doo-hwan in Myanmar in 1983. But Pyongyang has largely abandoned such overt tactics in the past two decades.

The U.N. Security Council is still weighing how to react to the North's belligerent moves that have earned Pyongyang criticism from the U.S., Europe, Russia and even the North's closest ally, China.

U.S. Defense Secretary Robert Gates said Saturday that North Korea's progress on nuclear weapons and long-range missiles is "a harbinger of a dark future" and has created an urgent need for more pressure on the reclusive communist government to change its ways.

Gates, speaking at an annual meeting of defense and security officials in Singapore, said Pyongyang's efforts pose the potential for an arms race in Asia that could spread beyond the region.

An incensed North Korea said last month that it was quitting the six-party negotiations after the U.N. Security Council condemned its April 5 rocket launch, widely believed to be a test of its long-range missile technology. The Security Council has imposed sanctions against the North over its first nuclear test in October 2006.

The six-party framework, which began in 2003, consists of the two Koreas, China, Japan, Russia and the United States.

ASEAN consists of Brunei, Cambodia, Indonesia, Laos, Malaysia, Myanmar, the Philippines, Singapore, Thailand and Vietnam.

In addition to the summit, a gathering of South Korean and Southeast Asian business leaders began Sunday with addresses by Lee and Abhisit, who both called for further cooperation to overcome the global economic crisis.

___

Associated Press writers Hyung-jin Kim in Seogwipo, Lara Jakes and Vijay Joshi in Singapore, Kwang-tae Kim in Seoul, and AP photographer Bullit Marquez in Seogwipo contributed to this report.

Lanus beats San Lorenzo 2-0 in Argentina

BUENOS AIRES, Argentina (AP) — Gonzalo Castillejos and Silvio Romero scored in the second half as Lanus earned a 2-0 home win over San Lorenzo on Saturday to move into third place in the Argentine Apertura football championship.

Castillejos scored in the 54th minute and Romero converted a penalty in the 62nd for Lanus, which trails leader Estudiantes by seven points.

San Lorenzo's title hopes are fading following a third straight defeat without scoring.

Also Saturday, Huracan drew 1-1 with All Boys, while defending champion Argentinos Juniors and Godoy Cruz finished scoreless and Newell's Old Boys drew 1-1 with Quilmes.

Estudiantes took a five-point lead atop the table with a 2-0 win over Olimpo on Friday and Arsenal is second after beating Banfield 1-0.

On Sunday, Independiente plays Racing Club, Velez Sarsfield takes on Colon and Tigre meets Boca Juniors. River Plate hosts Gimnasia on Monday.

Castillejos gave Lanus the lead over San Lorenzo after a corner dribbled across the six yard (meter) box for the striker to make a close-range finish.

San Lorenzo defender Jose Palomino tripped Romero in the box just after the hour mark and Romero sent Pablo Migliore the wrong way from the spot to extend the lead.

Elsewhere, reigning champion Argentinos Juniors drew 0-0 with Godoy Cruz to end a two-game winning streak and stay in the bottom half of the table. Argentinos went seven matches without a win at the start of its title defense.

Earlier Saturday, Jonathan Ferrari gave newly promoted All Boys the lead against Huracan in the 76th, but Dario Soplan equalized in the fourth minute of stoppage time.

Both clubs remain in the bottom half of the standings.

In the day's late match, Mauro Formica scored in the 30th minute for Newell's against Quilmes, before Danilo Gerlo prodded in the equalizer in the 60th.

Newell's defender Rolando Schiavi was sent off after receiving his second yellow card just before the final whistle.

The point moved Newell's into a share of fourth place with Velez Sarsfield. Quilmes improved a couple of spots to 17th.

The international dimensions of the Argentine default: the case of the Sovereign Debt Restructuring Mechanism

Introduction

Despite an excess of high-level discussions and agreements dedicated to strengthening international financial architecture, neither governments nor markets are nearer to solving the problems of transnational debt. This refers to "all the forms of debt across frontiers: all the liabilities incurred, and claims established, between institutions or individuals under one political jurisdiction" (Strange 1998a, 91-92). Up to now, transnational debt has been managed by the world's lender of last resort (LOLR), the International Monetary Fund (IMF). It should be underlined that the IMF has continued to govern over this increasingly complex phenomenon despite the lack of changes to its legal mandate or an international consensus on how transnational debt should be managed. The debate surrounding the creation of a competing institution--the Asian Monetary Fund--in the wake of the Asian crash of 1997 evidenced the competing views that exist on how crises should be addressed. The position of the US government has been that if complemented with proper institutions and best practices in the South, the Fund's role as LOLR is sufficient to deal with crises. This stance was thrown into question, however, when the Argentine government defaulted in December 2001 on most of its $141 billion debt, thereby creating the biggest sovereign default in history.

In November 2001, in response to the mounting economic problems in Argentina, and its apparently imminent default, the IMF's First Deputy Managing Director, Anne Krueger, put forward a new approach to dealing with sovereign debt, the Sovereign Debt Restructuring Mechanism (SDRM) (Eichengreen 2002a). The motivation behind this plan was to provide better incentives for debtors and creditors to agree on prompt, orderly, and predictable restructuring of unsustainable debt (International Monetary Fund 2003a). Specifically, the SDRM "would allow a country to come to the Fund and request a temporary standstill on the repayment of its debts, during which time it would negotiate a rescheduling or restructuring with its creditors" (given the Fund's consent) (International Monetary Fund 2001). It should be noted that since Krueger introduced the SDRM proposal, the restructuring framework has come under considerable attack from a diverse set of interests, including international creditors, non-governmental organizations, and the US Treasury Secretary. Not surprisingly, the new bankruptcy procedure for insolvent governments was not supported by the IMF's International Monetary and Financial Committee (IMFC)--a body that is responsible for advising, and reporting to, the Board of Governors--at the Annual Meeting of the World Bank and IMF in April 2003.

However, the lack of support for the SDRM does not mean that this policy is not worthy of critical reflection. There are at least three reasons why it is useful to understand the SDRM from a wider conceptual lens than has been used up to now. First, an analysis of the issues and problems involved in managing transnational debt thus far aids in our understanding of why the IMF and the US government have been balking regarding the financing of debt restructuring vis-a-vis Argentina. With such an understanding, the existing scholarship on the causes and consequences of the Argentine crisis could be complemented by a critical discussion of the underlying contradictions involved in managing transnational debt from an international political economy perspective.(1) Second, the debates surrounding the SDRM, most notably between the IMF and the US Treasury Department, significantly shape future policy directions of managing transnational debt since they reflect the more discriminating and conservative approach to multilateral assistance of the Bush administration (2001-present) under which aid would be provided only to countries with solid fundamentals and the size of aid packages would be limited (Eichengreen 2002b). Third, while the SDRM was struck down, the IMFC did nonetheless support a set of reforms restricting the Fund's rescue lending to crisis-hit countries and encouraging a more active role for the majority of creditors caught in a situation of sovereign bankruptcy.

Up till now, the literature on the SDRM has been dominated by heavily economistic and mainstream analyses (Eichengreen 2002a, 2002b; Akyuz 2002; Cooper 2002). The upshot of this has been that more critical questions, such as who benefits and why, have not been addressed.(2) This essay seeks to fill this void by casting more light on a largely neglected dimension of the SDRM debates, namely, the detrimental effects of constructing an imperative of capital account liberalization in the international economy and, relatedly, the growing reliance of emerging market economies, like Argentina, on private, short-term capital inflows to feed public debt. The main goal of this essay is to analyze the international discussion triggered by the Argentine case regarding the means to deal with the problem of sovereign default. As such, the focus of the discussion is not on Argentina per se, but on the significance of the SDRM vis-a-vis the assumption that open capital accounts are vital to achieving economic growth in the South, a central tenet of the neoliberal-led Washington consensus. This form of transnational debt management seems to aggravate at least two problems facing emerging markets. First, the increased dependence on capital account liberalization increases the vulnerability of middle-income countries--which receive the largest share of volatile, short-term capital flows--to external shocks or volatility in international markets. Second, in pursuing the IMF-led policy of capital account liberalization, these countries' governments--in order to attract and retain short-term capital flows--become more accountable to the demands of transnational financial capitals than to those whom they govern.

To set the stage for the central role of capital account liberalization in the IMF's policies and the inherent contradictions they pose for policy formation in the South, I will begin my discussion with an overview of the Washington consensus and the changing nature of capital flows vis-a-vis emerging market economies.

The Washington Consensus and the Growing Significance of Capital Account Liberalization

The fall of the Bretton Woods system in 1971 ushered in a new policy and ideological orientation in the United States known as neoliberalism. Neoliberalism is premised on the steadfast belief that political and social problems should be solved primarily through market-based mechanisms as opposed to state intervention. Neoliberalism quickly became the dominant policy of international financial institutions such as the IMF and World Bank, congealing into what many authors have referred to as the "Washington consensus." As former Senior Vice President and Chief Economist of the World Bank, Joseph Stiglitz, notes, the success of the consensus rests on its simplicity:

[I]ts policy recommendations could be administered by economists using little more than simple accounting frameworks. A few economic indicators--inflation, money supply growth, interest rates, as well as budget and trade deficits--could serve as the basis for a set of policy recommendations. Indeed, in some cases economists would fly into a country, look at and attempt to verify these data, and make macroeconomic recommendations for policy reforms all in the space of a couple of weeks. (Stiglitz 1998)

Through their insistence that debtor nations adopt export-led strategies (including a faster rate of production increase), minimize any restrictions on the activities of private market participants, and ensure tight fiscal discipline (draconian slash-and-burn policies vis-a-vis social spending), Structural Adjustment Policies (SAPs) helped bring about huge and continual resource transfers from debtor countries to the developed world. The emphasis on privatization and deregulation also attracted foreign capital investment to developing countries. According to a report by the Joint Economic Committee of the US Congress in the mid-1980s, while bank profits grew steadily during the debt crisis, the developing countries exposed to SAPs moved further into debt (Bienefeld 1993). For example, despite the widely believed "success" of Argentina's "Convertibility Plan," which effectively tied the peso to the US dollar, the country's foreign debt grew at record rates from $65 billion in 1991 to $160.2 billion in 2001 (Pettifor et al. 2001, 3). As I will show below, SAPs also assisted in creating a greater, not a lesser, dependency of Third World governments on global capital markets (as opposed to less volatile forms of debt: bilateral and multilateral aid), not to mention higher poverty rates than those registered before the debt crises of the early 1980s.

Capital account liberalization was a key element of the Washington consensus right from the early stages of SAPs. However, as the structure of capital inflows to certain countries in the global South (i.e., "the emerging market economies") underwent significant changes, so, too, did the emphasis placed on open capital accounts.(3) During the 1980s, for instance, financial flows consisted predominantly of longer-term foreign direct investment, usually in the form of takeovers of newly-privatized companies. By the mid-1980s, more powerful and less vulnerable financial players, such as mutual and pension funds, began to supplant traditional bank lending activities in both the private and public sectors. However, it was not until the early 1990s that the nature of capital flows began to change for emerging markets, including Argentina.

Financial flows have undergone at least three structural changes since the early 1990s (Griffith-Jones 1996). The first distinguishing feature was the sheer size of the capital flows. Between 1992 and 1993, for example, capital inflows reached an annual average of around $62 billion in Latin America, compared with the 1983-1990 period in which net capital inflows averaged only $10 billion a year. Second, official development finance, especially its largest component, bilateral aid, has lagged behind private flows (Ocampo 2001). Due to this lag, governments of emerging markets have grown more dependent on international financial players to fill their public and private coffers. For instance, by 1993, 74% of private foreign investment in Mexico, Brazil, Chile, Argentina, and Sri Lanka came from mutual funds and pension funds (Dillon 1997, 70). Put differently, in the 1980-85 period 66% of Latin American debt was to official creditors while the private creditors were represented by fewer than 20 banks. In contrast, by the late 1990s, private creditors accounted for approximately two-thirds of outstanding Latin American debt (International Monetary Fund 2002). According to the Executive Secretary of the UN Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean, Jose Antonio Ocampo, the majority of capital flows to the middle-income countries are not only more short-term (one year or less) than they were in the 1980s, but these countries also receive the highest concentration of the most volatile flows (Ocampo 2000). The increased disembedding of (highly esoteric) financial instruments from the real economy through technological innovation and liberalization processes constitutes the third change in financial flows. Although not divorced from the productive sphere, the steady intensification of financialization has meant that growth rates of turnover of financial assets are many times higher than the growth of any indicator of "real" activity (Altvater 2002). In other words, finance is no longer a means of facilitating the exchange of goods and services but has become an end in itself, largely feeding the yawning gap left by the trade and budget deficits. It should be noted that due to a mixture of crises in the South, along with the global economic slowdown, net debt flows have been negative for the past three years. However, a recent World Bank publication has stated that net debt flows are projected to be positive in 2003: "Gross capital market flows to developing countries are expected to rise to $155 billion in 2003 from $137 billion in 2002. By 2005, gross flows of bank lending and portfolio securities together are expected to rise to around $165 billion" (World Bank 2003, 45).

The upshot of these changes has been the creation of a highly complex and incredibly volatile form of transnational debt, including a plethora of private and public creditors and debtors, spanning across national boundaries. As Susan Strange notes, this form of debt includes

assets claimed by foreign shareholders in enterprises in another country, interbank loans across frontiers, bonds issued to non-nationals both by governments and other institutions and firms, as well as credits or guarantees extended by states or multilateral organizations like the IMF and World Bank or the regional development banks in Asia, the western hemisphere or Africa. (Strange 1998a, 91-92)

For example, Argentina's total debt in 1999 comprised the following sources: IMF credit (3%), multilateral credit (10%), bilateral (4%), short-term debt (21%), private creditors (62%) (e.g., US institutional investors, European and Japanese retail investors) (Pettifor et al. 2001, 19).

Despite the intricacy of transnational debt in the post-Bretton Woods era, the IMF, acting as the world's lender of last resort (LOLR), was the only institutional mechanism in place. Given the steady rise of private capital flows to the South as a key source of developing financing, why didn't international policymakers create an institutional framework to deal adequately with these changes? The answer to this question must be located in existing power structures in the global political economy. As Susan Strange reminds us, while the phenomenon of borrowing--getting money today in exchange for money tomorrow--is economic, the management of such transactions is political (Strange 1998a, 92).

Governing Transnational Debt: The Role of the IMF

Corresponding to the changes in capital flows and the increase in power of transnational creditors in the South, institutions tied to the Washington consensus, such as the IMF, began to emphasize--in the form of conditionalities--the need for debtor countries to commit to capital account liberalization in order to achieve "economic progress." It should be highlighted that the new focus of free capital mobility did not replace other features of the SAPs. Instead, the push for capital account liberalization was to complement the existing market-led prescriptions of the Washington consensus, such as trade liberalization, fiscal austerity, deregulation of labour markets, privatization of public enterprises, and so on. Joseph Stiglitz describes the IMF's new mandate in the following manner:

[W]hile [the new directive] may have been quiet, it was hardly subtle: from serving global economic interests to serving the interests of global finance. Capital market liberalization may not have contributed to global economic stability, but it did open up vast new markets for Wall Street. (Stiglitz 2002, 207)

For instance, prior to the Asian crisis of 1997, the Interim Committee of the IMF (now the International Monetary and Finance Committee) attempted to revise the Fund's charter to impose upon its members a legal obligation to open capital accounts (International Monetary Fund 1997, 8).

Against this backdrop, we can observe a shift in the IMF's main role from promoting the restoration and expansion of trade flows during the Bretton Woods era (1944-1971) to explicitly advancing the cause of enduring capital market integration. The role of the Fund has shifted from overseeing exchange rate stability in the dollar-gold pegged rate regime to a financial intermediary in which it facilitates stability around the world by acting as a bridge between net lenders and borrowers. Creditors, on the one hand, rely on the judgement calls of the IMF, whether through its transparency exercise entailed in the Fund's Dissemination Standards Bulletin Board, or through its Public Information Notices, which are published following the so-called "Article IV Consultations," i.e., the IMF Executive Board's assessment of countries' macroeconomic and financial situations. It should be noted that this assessment is based on a neoliberal benchmark, or, in other words, that these assessments evaluate to what extent the debtor countries have implemented the principles of the Washington consensus. However, governments of debtor countries aspire to high marks on these reporting exercises since a favorable report card from the IMF acts as an important "seal of approval" to obtain new loans, or simply to rollover existing loans, from the international financial markets.

It must be kept in mind that the IMF remains without a firm legal mandate in the post-Bretton Woods era (Pauly 1999). Seen in this light, the claim by the IMF that it should play the role of lender of last resort must be critically evaluated, particularly in view of our discussion of the SDRM (Pauly 1999). Before embarking on this discussion, it is important to ask some questions about underlying power relations. Which member state is promoting such a role? Why? It is not difficult to trace structural power within the IMF to the government department that makes the largest financial contribution, i.e., the US Treasury Secretary.(4) The Fund's rule of global lender of last resort is not new, however. In 1962, with the creation of the General Arrangement to Borrow (GAB), ground rules were established regarding when, and on what terms, the Fund could lend to member states. As Susan Strange highlights, the word "agreement" is conspicuous in its absence from the GAB, signaling that its design was the creation of the US and France, with Holland and Belgium acting as supporters to the Arrangement (Strange 1998b, 165). Over the years, the GAB has been revised several times in order to increase the limit available for bailing out countries in need, particularly subsequent to the 1980 debt crises in the South. In the aftermath of the Mexican peso crisis, and the problems the Clinton administration experienced in responding to it, the 1995 Halifax Summit called on the G10 and other wealthy countries to help double the existing amount of financial arrangements available to the IMF under the GAB. In November 1998, the New Arrangement to Borrow (NAB) was established, in the words of the IMF,

to forestall or cope with an impairment of the international monetary system or to deal with an exceptional threat to the stability of that system.... The total amount of resources available to the IMF under the NAB and GAB combined is about $45 billion, double the amount available under the GAB alone. (International Monetary Fund 2002)

The latter sum seems to pale in comparison with public debt burdens of countries like Argentina that were hovering well over four times this amount.

At a deeper level, the NAB reveals an attempt by the US government to maintain control over crisis management in the South. As I will show later in the discussion, this same impulse is evident in the debates surrounding the SDRM. First, the NAB, like its counterpart the GAB, is based on a putative interstate consensus. Hence the lack of a legal mandate attached to the NAB and the choice of the word "Arrangement," not "New Agreement to Borrow," seemed to replicate US structural power in the global political economy. Second, and relatedly, if the IMF was looking to expand its financial resources, why not consider Japan's proposal in September 1997 to set up an Asian Monetary Fund (AMF)? As C. Fred Bergsten notes, an AMF would have not only eased the financial burden of the IMF but also, given that Asian policymakers would have treated it as "their own institution," an AMF would have acted more efficiently in terms of crisis response (Bergsten 1998). Some authors have argued that, because evidence suggests that contagion is a regional phenomenon, a regional monetary fund that was more sensitive to the institutional and legal particularities of East Asia would have been far more effective in terms of surveillance than a more globally oriented IMF (Rajan 2000). Moreover, according to the Asian Development Bank, the estimated potential financial mobilization of the AMF would have been about $100 billion--over twice the amount the IMF raised through the NAB (Rajan 2000). Regardless of these arguments, the conception of the AMF was immediately struck down by the US (along with China) largely due to the threat an Asian lender of last resort would have had on American structural power in the region (Wade and Veneroso 1998a, 1998b; cf. Soederberg 2002).

The above discussion draws attention not only to the political decisions involved in the existing institutional arrangement for crisis management, but also to the dominant neoliberal assumption underpinning the management of transnational debt: open capital accounts. The US government's refusal to allow for a competing institution that could respond to debt crisis in the East Asian region was largely rooted in the potential damage of the AMF vis-a-vis the imperative of capital account liberalization. The East Asian region has historically favoured state intervention to deal with market imbalances, as opposed to the central tenets of the Washington consensus. Moreover, key countries in the region (Malaysia, Taiwan, China, Hong Kong, Singapore) have at one time or another implemented the use of capital controls, some believe successfully, to protect their economies from the whims of short-term financial flows. More recently, the US government's strong aversion to capital controls has expressed itself in the US-Chile and US-Singapore free trade agreements, in which the US government has imposed severe restrictions on the use of capital controls as a precondition for signing the agreements (US House of Representatives Committee on Financial Services 2003). For the US government, previous use by the Chilean and Singaporean governments of capital restrictions is "bad financial policy, bad trade policy, and bad foreign policy" (Bhagwati and Tarullo 2003).

There are issues of power involved as well in the political decisions to maintain the status quo. Jagdish Bhagwati, an influential trade economist at MIT, coined the term the Wall Street-Treasury Complex to highlight the growing power of the US. For Bhagwati,

Wall Street has become a very powerful influence in terms of seeking markets everywhere.... Just like the old days there was this "military-industrial-complex", nowadays there is a "Wall Street-Treasury complex."... Wall Street views are very dominant in terms of the kind of world you want to see. They want the ability to take capital in and out freely. So the IMF finally gets a role for itself, which is underpinned by maintaining complete freedom on the capital account. (Bhagwati, in Wade and Veneroso 1998a, 18-19)

Yet, as I will discuss below, the Wall Street-Treasury Complex rests on fragile foundations. The assumption that financial liberalization will lead to prosperity and economic stability for the global South has been seriously discredited, not only by recent debacles, but also by rising poverty and indigence rates in the IMF's pin-up economies, most recently Argentina and Turkey (Soederberg 2002; Akyuz 2002). Moreover, as the Argentine crisis has most strongly revealed, the self-imposed role of the IMF as the world's LOLR has done little to address the institutional weakness involved in managing transnational debt. Instead, this stance ensures the central role of the IMF in promoting open capital accounts in the South (Fischer 1999). Before turning to this discussion, however, it is useful to grasp the logic guiding the Fund's push for complete freedom on the capital account.

The core logic surrounding Washington's push for capital account liberalization rests on the basic assumption that international financial markets are not only inherently rational in nature, but also lead to mutual gain. Liberalized capital flows, for instance, are thought to create greater welfare benefits because foreign savings supplement the domestic resource base. As a result, this leads to a larger capital stock and places the economy on a potentially higher growth path. Free trade in capital, through international borrowing and lending, actually helps lower the costs of the inter-temporal misalignments that periodically arise between the patterns of production and consumption. Put plainly, capital inflows permit national economies to pay for imports in the present with exports in the future.

Another benefit from financial liberalization is believed to be that the sharing and diversification of risks that otherwise would not be possible become feasible (Guitan 1997, 22; Felix 2002). Critically, since capital markets are inherently rational, they will enter those countries that demonstrate sound regulatory practices such as balanced budgets, low inflation, market liberalization, and stable exchange rates. According to this line of reasoning, markets act as a disciplinary force, which can punish profligate governments through investment strikes and capital flight (Gill and Law 1993). It is interesting to note that the inherent rationality of financial participants lies at the base of the SDRM, particularly in its concern of avoiding any moral hazard in future IMF bailouts. Is this conventional wisdom correct or just convenient? Does the liberalization of cross-border transactions in capital markets lead to greater prosperity? Or has financialization merely led to a situation whereby hot money can freely flow into emerging markets to exploit interest rate differentials or other speculative ventures, while the productive sectors of these countries go through further forms of de-industrialization?

Policy Paradoxes in the Era of Financialization

It is worth mentioning at the outset that the assumption that market actors are inherently rational is not an uncontested view. David Felix suggests that this position does not have

general backing from more basic theorizing about the stability of competitive market economies. Rather, the theorizing indicates that liberated financial markets are inherently prone to destabilizing dynamics that can also destabilize aggregate production, trade, and employment in such economies. (Felix 2002)(5)

Mary Ann Haley's work echoes Felix's conclusions when she argues that neither the assumption that an adequate number of investors create the most favorable conditions for competition nor that in a "fair and efficient market investors have access to roughly the same information and react similarly and 'rationally' within the confines of profit-maximization reflect the present reality of investment in emerging markets" (Haley 1999, 76). It is necessary to take a closer look at the political effects of the adherence to open capital accounts in the South.

The Herculean task of signaling creditworthiness to global financial players by adhering to the conventional wisdom of the Washington consensus and placating domestic social strife has proved to be increasingly difficult for governments of middle-income countries. In particular, the tension between the principle of national self-determination and the neoliberal principle of capital account liberalization--as part and parcel of the neoliberal package of reforms--has contributed to a legitimacy crisis in many emerging markets. The changing nature of capital flows to emerging market economies has had important political ramifications for governments of debtor countries, or what I refer to as a policy paradox. Ilene Grabel identifies at least two negative and mutually reinforcing effects that financial flows have on national policy formation in the emerging markets: (1) the imposition of constraints on policy autonomy; and (2) the creation of greater vulnerability to the economy to risk, financial volatility, and crisis (Grabel 1996).

First, as governments of emerging markets embrace foreign portfolio investment (stock and bond purchases) as a source of financing, their exposure to the risks of capital flight increases. As mentioned above, the Asian crisis has clearly demonstrated that even sound economic fundamentals (e.g., low inflation, high savings rates, falling unemployment numbers) are no guarantee that highly mobile capital will not choose to flee en masse in adverse circumstances. Despite the robust macroeconomic equilibria and high rate of domestic savings, for instance, these 'miracle economies' buckled under the quick exit of foreign funds. Indeed, the changing nature of financial flows to emerging markets has made it increasingly difficult to protect the domestic economy against the devastating effects of contagion and capital flight. Chakravarthi notes that a

shift of 1% in equity holdings by an institutional investor in one of the G-7 countries away from domestic equity would be slightly more than a 1% share of total market capitalization, but would constitute the equivalent of 27% of market capitalization in emerging Asian economies, and over 66% of Latin American equity markets. (Chakravarthi 1998)

Regarding the second point, to continually attract creditors, most of which stem from highly mobile sources of foreign capital, governments of emerging markets must send positive signals to investors about their credibility and market-friendliness, such as degrees of capital mobility, labour and production costs, and political stability (Maxfield 1996). Thus the need to continuously signal creditworthiness to global financial markets has not only limited the scope of policy autonomy of states in emerging markets, but has generated stark tension between the accountability of policymakers to the needs of transnational capitals as opposed to those people it governs (Gill and Law 1993). In this way, in order to attract this crucial source of public financing, governments are pressured to enter into a "pact with the devil" whereby market credibility assumes a central position in policymaking in such areas as exchange and interest rates as well as through tight fiscal policies. The latter can begin to conflict or even take precedence over other domestic concerns, especially the needs of subordinate segments of the population, such as the working class, urban and rural poor. Despite the attempts by the Argentine government to adhere to market-led restructuring demanded by the IMF, poverty rates increased dramatically since the 1990s. In fact, according to official figures, 57.5% of Argentines now live on or below the poverty line.

The corollary of the above is the growing structural power of transnational financial capitals, such as institutional investors (hedge, pension, and mutual funds), vis-a-vis the states in the South. Indeed, Geoffrey Underhill astutely notes that the growth in capital volatility and mobility acts to constrain the policy-making autonomy of elected governments, particularly with regard to exchange rate and monetary policy, but also with fiscal (taxation) and social policies. For Underhill, these tensions have resulted in a substantial "legitimacy deficit," further exacerbated by the need to adjust to a constant "global restructuring" (Underhill 1997, 19).

The tension described by Underhill takes a distinct form of expression in the South, particularly in countries like Argentina. For example, in her extensive study of investment behaviour of money managers, Mary Ann Haley suggests that investors, attracted to those countries that rapidly implement and maintain intense economic reforms while simultaneously controlling political opposition to these measures, may continue to find liberal democracy not only unnecessary, but also perhaps even contrary to their interests (Haley 1999). Above all, and especially during times of crisis, governments are required to maintain political stability. These conditions can readily lead to increased forms of coercion and other expressions of authoritarianism aimed at quelling overt manifestations of class conflict so as to attract and maintain capital inflows. The limits placed on policy autonomy and the growing priority given to transnational finance in terms of neoliberal policies can increasingly constrain political space for the articulation of subordinate voices. To illustrate, over the past year and a half, a number of factories ("fabricas ocupadas") across Argentina have been taken over and run by their workers. Eager to protect the virtues of private property and reinforce the perception that Argentina possesses a disciplined and inexpensive workforce, the state has responded to this and other forms of popular organization with increasing violence and repression (Klein 2003; Dinerstein 2003a, 2003b; Rock 2002).(6) While this strategy may temporarily soothe the jittery nerves of Argentina's international creditors, the upshot of growing state-led oppression will only be to increase, as opposed to mitigate, the ongoing legitimacy crisis of the state vis-a-vis civil society organizations.

Seen from the above angle, the limitations placed on policy leeway through the adherence to capital account liberalization drastically narrow attempts by ruling classes to deal adequately with the mounting social discontent that threatens the reproduction of neoliberal rule in the South. In response, many governments in emerging market countries have begun to make explicit their discontent with the neoliberal paradigm (i.e., the Washington consensus) so as to reproduce their position of power. Indeed, as Sader rightfully observes, the sickness of the economies in Latin America is not only accompanied with the deterioration of the social fabric, but also with a growing dissatisfaction with US-led economic growth paradigms.

[President] Clinton left his successor with a situation very different from the one he had inherited. George W. Bush faces a Latin America in its worst crisis since the 1930s. In states with fragile economies, social structures are fragmented, with many people deprived of basic human rights. In Argentina, Haiti, Uruguay, Nicaragua, Peru, Paraguay, Venezuela, Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador: actual or potential crises are increasing. (Sader 2003)

Interestingly, the SDRM does not consider mitigating the power of capital account liberalization. Increased policy autonomy, for example, is important to help these countries overcome what Jose Antonio Ocampo refers to as the state's legitimacy crisis (Ocampo 2002). Increased autonomy is only obtainable, however, if the key source constraining domestic policy-making--i.e., capital account liberalization--is either removed or substantially hindered. In more concrete terms, Ocampo is arguing that developing countries should maintain national autonomy in at least two critical areas: the management of capital account and the choice of exchange rate regime (Ocampo 2000).

The SDRM stands in contrast to Ocampo's position, however. As I will argue below, because both the IMF and the US Treasury Secretary view the problems facing emerging markets--and, in particular, bankrupt states such as Argentina--as caused by bad government policy as opposed to destabilizing capital inflows, their solution is in part to be found in disciplining governments with more, as opposed to less, neoliberal restructuring. In the words of Joseph Stiglitz:

The US Treasury had during the early 1990s heralded the global triumph of capitalism. Together with the IMF, it had told countries that followed the 'right policies'--the Washington Consensus policies--they would be assured of growth. The East Asia crisis cast doubt on this new world-view unless it could be shown that the problem was not with capitalism, but with the Asian countries and their bad policies. The IMF and the US Treasury had to argue that the problem was not with the reforms--implementing liberalization of capital markets... but with the fact that the reforms had not been carried out far enough. (Stiglitz 2002, 213, emphasis in the original)

Let us now turn to the two key debates surrounding the implications of the SDRM to deal with the issue of transnational debt.

Emerging Solutions to the Transnational Debt Problem: The Sovereign Debt Restructuring Mechanism (SDRM)

"The debtors and how best to deal with them is surely one of the continuing but unresolved issues for the international financial system." Susan Strange (1998a, 91)

At first glance, the US government and the IMF may appear to have acted inconsistently regarding the countries, circumstances, and conditions in which to effect bailouts. In 2000, a year before the Argentine meltdown, the Treasury department was quick to sign over a $16-billion bailout package when Turkey defaulted, after only 14 months of currency peg. In August 2001, just a few months prior to Argentina's default, the US government supported a large stand-by loan package to the country. More recently, and after the Argentine meltdown, in August 2002, the IMF came to the rescue of Argentina's larger neighbour, offering Brazil $30 billion to calm the country's roiled markets. According to Brazil's central bank, its debt-to-GDP (Gross Domestic Product) ratio was 61.9% by the end of July 2002 (Weisbrot and Baker 2002). It should be recalled that prior to the Brazilian debt crisis of 1982, its debt service ratio was 63.3% in 1979 (Kapstein 1994, 72). Yet the IMF did not rush to rescue the largest-ever sovereign default in dollar terms that occurred in December 2001. White House and Treasury officials say that by letting Argentina suffer the consequences of its own mismanagement, the US government wishes to send out a clear signal that it "would be a reluctant financial firefighter and that the markets should not bet on a bailout" (International Herald Tribune 2002). Why the discrepancy? A substantial part of the answer to this question lies in self-interest on the part of the US. As Susan Strange observed over two decades ago,

[w]ithout its ever being stated in so many words, the Fund's operational decisions made its resources available neither to those in greatest need nor to those with the best record of good behaviour in keeping to the rules, but paradoxically to those members whose financial difficulties were most likely to jeopardise the stability of the international monetary system. (Susan Strange as quoted in Pauly 1997, 115)

Given the growing levels of indebtedness of developing countries, as well as the fact that the key players in this debt load are institutional investors in the private sector, guaranteeing the stability of the international monetary system today no longer implies bail-outs, but rather arrangements for market participants to have more direct control over policy formation in the global South. Strange observes that after the 1980 debt crisis the ruling classes of many developing countries decided to neither trade nor borrow from the global economy, thereby "doing their best to be self-sufficient, autonomous and, as some argued, free" (Strange 1994, 112). She goes on to note that

[a]nxiety to keep the debtors inside the financial structure despite their difficulties was all the greater if the debtor country was large, was a substantial importer of Western goods, and was host to a large number of Western transnational corporations--none of whom were anxious to cope with a decoupled debtor country. (ibid.)

For the US, this has also implied more direct American control over the IMF. During the spring 2002 meetings of the IMF and World Bank in Washington, DC, the G-7 finance ministers and the IMF's monetary and finance committee endorsed a twin-track approach to improving procedures for dealing with sovereign bankruptcies. It is important to highlight that what the G-7 ministers received, however, was a watered-down version of what was originally proposed by the IMF's Deputy Managing Director, Anne Krueger, in November 2001.

Broadly, Krueger's original proposal suggests a "sovereign debt restructuring mechanism" (SDRM-1) that would entail a new international legal framework based on the features of domestic bankruptcy proceedings in the private sector. This was essentially aimed at creating a binding set of laws through which crisis-stricken countries could halt panics and keep investors from pulling their money out of the nation--buying time for political leaders to work out debts in an orderly fashion--much like Chapter 11 of US bankruptcy law. Under the proposed SDRM-1, the IMF would play a central role by determining which countries would be eligible to participate in the SDRM and by ensuring that member countries adhere to the procedures laid out by the SDRM framework. The SDRM-1 described a process in which countries in crisis would call a halt to debt payments as they negotiated with private sector lenders, under the jurisdiction of a new international judicial panel. During these negotiations, the IMF effectively protects the debtor country from litigation. The conditions of repayment after a country declared bankruptcy would be negotiated among the creditors by supermajority. Supermajority refers to a situation in which 60-75% of the creditors agree to the terms of restructuring, which would then be binding for the rest of the creditors and, of course, the debtor country. The proposed role of the IMF would be to oversee voting and adjudicate disputes in this process. As Krueger noted, "the Fund's role would be essential to the success of such a system" (Miller 2002, 4). For the SDRM-1 to be realized, however, the IMF's Articles of Agreement (i.e., its constitution) would have had to be subject to reform. As noted earlier, for any such change to occur, the US, which wields veto power, has to agree with these changes.

However, the US government did not agree with the conditions set out in the SDRM-1. After heavy criticism from the Treasury Undersecretary, Krueger revised her proposal (SDRM-2) so as to enhance the role and power of creditors. Essentially, the SDRM-2 was more in line with Taylor's insistence on a decentralized, market-based approach that was based on a broader use of "collective action clauses" (CACs) in bonds issued by sovereign governments' provisions. CACs entail provisions that allow a supermajority of bondholders to approve a process which is believed to make it easier to restructure debt by allowing a majority of creditors to impose a deal. A supermajority of creditors is deemed important as it overcomes the problem of "collection action," which occurs when individual creditors

consider that their interests are best served by preventing what is termed a 'grab race,' in which creditors try to get the best deal possible from the debtor government so as to enforce their claim as quickly as possible. This grab race is believed to hinder other creditors and thus may lead them in capturing the limited assets available. (Boorman 2002)

It is this feature of the SDRM-2 that was touted during the recent World Bank IMF Annual Meetings in April 2003, at which the IMFC welcomed the inclusion of CACs by several countries, most recently Mexico, in international sovereign bond issues. The IMFC also welcomed the announcement that, by June 2003, those European Union countries issuing bonds under foreign jurisdictions will include CACs. In fact, the IMFC goes on to state that it looks forward to the inclusion of CACs in international bond issues becoming standard market practice, and calls on the IMF to promote the voluntary inclusion of CACs in the context of its surveillance practices. Obviously this would ensure that countries adhere to neoliberal policies laid out in the Washington consensus (International Monetary Fund 2003b).

Krueger's modified SDRM-2 effectively reduced the amount of control the IMF had over how the standstill (a temporary suspension of payments) would work, or even how debts would be restructured. A caveat is in order here. Despite the fact that the role of the IMF is downplayed, it should be recalled that the ability of the Fund to provide a "seal of approval," and thereby signal the creditworthiness of a debtor nation to its international creditors, makes the Fund an integral and coercive feature in not only the negotiation of debt but also the reproduction of the status of private financial markets. Moreover, embracing the notion that a near-default on sovereign debt may be worked out through legal frameworks and an IMF-centred international agreement plays an important role in both normalizing and disciplining the power of transnational capital over sovereign states (International Monetary Fund 2003c). In doing so, the Fund also serves to put forward a particular version of reality that stands in contrast with contesting views, most notably the many voices who have been calling for debt cancellation over the past few decades.(7)

It should be underlined that the SDRM-2 was neither transparent nor inclusive. The only ostensibly independent forum attached to the SDRM-2 process was the proposed Sovereign Debt Dispute Resolution Forum (SDDRF). According to Krueger, the SDDRF was to be set up as "a legal body whose functions would be to register claims and resolve disputes [and] would be independent of the Fund and its Executive Board, in parallel with approaches used in other organizations" (International Monetary Fund 2003c). Nevertheless, it should be noted that the powers of the SDDRF were limited in two ways. First, although the IMF had stated that the SDDRF should be independent of the Fund, it had also highlighted that it would retain a veto over SDDRF decisions. Second, the SDRM-2 did not include citizen participation in the resolution processes of financial crises. On the one hand, the SDRM-2 preferred a laissez-faire approach, allowing market participants more power in the default procedures. This approach was clearly designed to increase the coercive power of transnational capital over debtor countries. Private financial institutions, led by their association, the Institute of International Finance, played a tactical game of supporting collective action clauses in the apparent hope of killing the plan for a judicial mechanism that would in effect reduce their power (Financial Times, 2002a). On the other hand, as is clear from its response to the Meltzer Commission mentioned earlier, the Treasury did not want the IMF to assume a life of its own,(8) nor does it want to see the creation of a new and truly global financial institution that could oversee such processes, as this could entail the threat of moving toward a multilateral as opposed to a unilateral form of norm-creating and decision-making processes.

It should also be highlighted that the official debates on the SDRM have excluded developing countries. In fact, up until the Annual Meeting of the IMF and World Bank in early autumn 2002 (which included the G-7 finance ministers), official discussions surrounding sovereign debt default have taken place exclusively between the Fund and the US Treasury. Given the importance of this issue to industrialized countries, acting on behalf of the interests of transnational capitals who have supplied the credit to emerging markets, the SDRM was not raised for discussion at the United Nations Financing for Development Conference at Monterrey, Mexico, in March 2002, despite the so-called inclusionary and democratic nature of the innovative gathering, involving civil society organizations, the IMF, the World Bank, the World Trade Organization, the G-7 countries, and the developing world (Soederberg 2002). Indeed, a fair, independent, and transparent process for negotiating debt restructuring would prove fatal to the disciplinary effects involved in sovereign bankruptcy. Neither the debtor country nor its citizens should have a voice in the negotiations. An act of exclusion, as many Argentines know too well, is necessary to bring together "like-minded" groups and individuals to the table.

The SDRM is also reserved for what the IMF deems as "important" emerging market economies, and thus is not applied across the board to all classes of debtors, such as the Highly Indebted Poor Countries (Greenhill 2002). More importantly, the debates surrounding the SDRM seem to normalize sovereign debt default which is a reality for Argentina, and may equally become one for Uruguay, and perhaps Brazil, with countless more to follow. Indeed, the fact that international policymakers are seriously debating the issue portends that default is to be a regular occurrence in the world economy. Relatedly, another feature of the debate that is neglected is that sovereign debt default runs contrary to the neoliberal logic that unfettered market freedom leads to economic viability and prosperity for the South. Indeed, the very fact that sovereign debt default is even occurring doesn't seem to be problematized in the SDRM debates.

Conclusion

All in all, the debates on the SDRM do little to further the interests of stability and social justice in countries like Argentina, but instead seek to strengthen the power of international creditors vis-a-vis sovereign states. Indeed, despite their differences, there exists a significant concurrence between the IMF and US Treasury Secretary with regard to two overlapping areas of debt restructuring. First, there is a growing consensus within the Bush administration and the IMF that the way forward is through "selective bailouts." The latter reflects the Bush administration's position that crisis management needs to be complemented by crisis prevention (US Department of Treasury 2002). Second, and relatedly, the key to preventing crises is by removing the moral hazard problem.(9) For Krueger and Taylor, the existing system of crisis resolution relies too heavily on bailout loans, which in turn creates a moral hazard problem. Moral hazard stipulates that the awareness that the IMF will bail out countries in the event of a financial crisis makes the crisis more likely to occur for two reasons. On the one hand, creditors are more willing to lend to high-risk debtor nations. On the other hand, the presence of the IMF weakens pressure on governments to pursue policies--such as fiscal restraint and prudent financial supervision and regulation--that could help prevent crises (Lane and Philips 2001).

The difficulty with the solutions proposed by the SDRM debates is that continued adherence by the ruling classes in the South to neoliberal tenets have become increasingly difficult to pursue, especially given the narrowing social basis for the neoliberal project in the wake of ever-widening income inequality and less and less accountability of governments to civil society. Drawing on 2002 data from the United Nations Economic Commission on Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC), Emir Sader points out that the number of people living below the poverty threshold in Latin America increased from 120 million in 1980 to 214 million in 2001 (43% of the population), with 92.8 million (18.6%) in conditions of destitution (Sader 2003). It remains highly questionable whether the proposals put forward by the SDRM debates will impede this trend (World Bank 2000, 3).

In all, the SDRM debates seem to reflect the general characteristic of how crisis-hit countries have been dealt with by the IMF over the past two decades. Three features come to mind. First, and foremost, financial liberalization is posited as a desirable policy because, like trade liberalization, it leads to economic growth and stability. Second, bad policies pursued by debtor nations, not the actions of the IMF nor those of banks or speculators, are seen as the root of the crisis (Schuler 2002). Third, and related to this neoclassical assumption, it is believed that debtor countries should be exposed more directly to the exigencies of transnational finance so that they may be forced to undertake market-based solutions to their current economic and political problems. What the SDRM debates--and the subsequent refusal of the IMFC to implement the framework proposed by Krueger--highlight is that Susan Strange's prescient remark is still applicable. Strange noted a few years before the world's largest sovereign default in Argentina that while "the evolution of that system has changed the nature of the debt problem... neither governments nor markets are any nearer a final solution to the question of how to manage transnational debt than they were in the 1980s" (Strange 1998a, 91).

Works Cited

Akyuz, Yilmaz. 2002. Reforming the global financial architecture: Issues and proposals. London: Zed Books.

Altvater, Elmar. 2002. The growth obsession. In Socialist register, edited by Leo Panitch and Colin Leys, 73-92. London: Merlin Press.

Bergsten, Fred C. 1998. Reviving the "Asian Monetary Fund." International Economic Policy Briefs. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics. Available at: <http://www.iie.com/policybriefs/news98-8.htm>.

Bhagwati, J., and D. Tarullo. 2003. Ban on capital controls is a bad trade off. Financial Times, 17 March. Available at: <http://www.tradeobservatory.org/News/index.cfm?ID=4220>.

Bienefeld, Manfred. 1993. Structural adjustment: Debt collection device or development policy? Paper prepared for Sophia University Lectures on Structural Adjustment: Past, Present and Future. Tokyo: Sophia University, 24-25 November. Mimeo.

Boorman, Jack. 2002. Sovereign debt restructuring: Where stands the debate? Speech delivered at a conference cosponsored by the CATO Institute and The Economist, New York, 17 October. Available at <http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2002/101702.htm>.

Carerra, N. I., and M.C. Cotarelo. 2003. Social struggles in present day Argentina. Bulletin of Latin American Research 22.2: 201-213.

Chakravarthi, R. 1998. Institutional funds--the main channel for market turbulence. Third World Economics 187/188 (16 June-15 July). Also published in the South-North Development Monitor. Available at: <http://www.twnside.org.sg/title/main-cn.htm>.

Cooper, R. 2002. Chapter 11 for countries? Foreign Affairs 81.4: 90-104.

Damodaran, Sumangala. 2000. Capital account convertibility: Theoretical issues and policy options. In Global finance: New thinking on regulating speculative capital markets, edited by Walden Bello, Nicola Bullard, and Kamal Malhotra, 159-176. London: Zed Books.

Dillon, John. 1997. Turning the tide: Confronting the money traders. Ottawa: Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives.

Dinerstein, A. C. 2003a. The battle of Buenos Aires: Crises, insurrection and the reinvention of politics in Argentina. Historical Materialism 10.4: 5-38.

-----. 2003b. [Symbol Not Transcribed]Que se vayan todos! Popular insurrection and the Asambleas Barriales in Argentina. Bulletin of Latin American Research 22.2: 187-200.

The Economist. 2002. Economics focus: Sovereign bankruptcies. 6 April.

Eichengreen, Barry. 2002a. Financial crises and what to do about them. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

-----. 2002b. Crisis prevention and management: Any new lessons from Argentina and Turkey? Background paper for the World Bank's Global Development Finance 2002. Washington, DC: World Bank.

Felix, David. 2002. The economic case against free capital mobility. In Debating the global financial architecture, edited by L. E. Armijo, 126-158. Albany: State University of New York Press.

Financial Times. 2002a. G7 'breakthrough' on debt default. 28/29 September.

-----. 2002b. US scorns IMF plan for bankrupt governments. 6/7 April.

Fischer, S. 1999. On the need for an international lender of last resort. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Available at: <http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/1999/010399.htm>.

Gill, Stephen, and David Law. 1993. Global hegemony and the structural power of capital. In Gramsci, historical materialism and international relations, edited by S. Gill, 93-124. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Grabel, I. 1996. Marketing the third world: The contradictions of portfolio investment in the global economy. World Development 24.11: 1761-1776.

Greenhill, Romilly. 2002. IMF Meetings give go-ahead for bankruptcy plan--but on whose terms? Jubilee 2000 UK, 1 October. Available at <http://www.jubilee2000uk.org/analysis/articles/imf011002.htm>.

Griffith-Jones, S. 1996. International capital flows to Latin America. In The new economic model in Latin America and its impact on income distribution and poverty, edited by Victor Bulmer-Thomas, 127-143. London: Macmillan.

Guitan, Manuel. 1997. Reality and the logic of capital flow liberalization. In Capital controls in emerging economies, edited by C. P. Ries and R. J. Sweeney, 189-244. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

Haley, Mary Ann. 1999. Emerging market makers: The power of institutional investors. In Financial globalization and democracy in emerging markets, edited by L. E. Armijo, 74-90. London: Macmillan.

International Herald Tribune. 2002. Argentina faces harder U.S. line. 7 January.

International Monetary Fund. 1997. IMF builds on initiatives to meet challenges of globalization. IMF Survey. Washington, DC: IMF.

-----. 2001. A new approach to sovereign debt restructuring. Address by Anne Krueger, First Deputy Managing Director, International Monetary Fund, delivered at the National Economists' Club Annual Members' Dinner, American Enterprise Institute. Washington, DC: IMF. Available at: <www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2001/112601.htm>.

-----. 2002. General arrangements to borrow (GAB) and new arrangements to borrow (NAB): A factsheet. November. <http://www.imf.org/external/np/exr/facts/gabnab.htm>.

-----. 2003a. Proposals for a sovereign debt restructuring mechanism (SDRM): A factsheet. Washington, DC: IMF. Available at: <www.imf.org/external/np/exr/facts/sdrm.htm>.

-----. 2003b. Press release from IMFC--Annual Meeting April 2003. Washington, DC: IMF. Available at: <http://www.imf.org/external/np/sec/pr/2003/pr0350.htm>.

-----. 2003c. Sovereign debt restructuring: Messy or messier? Speech by Anne Krueger, Deputy Managing Director of the IMF, Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, 4 January 2003. Washington, DC: IMF. Available at: <http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2003/010403.htm>.

Kapstein, Ethan. 1994. Governing the global economy: International finance and the state. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Klein, Naomi. 2003. Snapshot of a nation. The Guardian, 28 April.

Lane, Timothy, and Stephen Philips. 2001. IMF financing and moral hazard. Financing & Development 28:2. Available at: <http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2001/06/lane.htm>.

Maxfield, Sylvia. 1996. Gatekeepers of growth: The international political economy of central banking in developing countries. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Miller, Marcus. 2002. Sovereign debt restructuring: New articles, new contracts--or no change? International Economics Policy Briefs, No. PB-2-3, April.

Mussa, Michael. 2002. Argentina and the fund: From triumph to tragedy. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.

Ocampo, J. A. 2000. A broad agenda for international financial reform. In Financial globalization and the emerging economies, edited by J. A. Ocampo, Stefano Zamagni, Ricardo Ffrench-Davis, and Carlo Pietrobelli, 41-62. Santiago: ECLAC.

-----. 2001. A broad agenda for international financial reform. Paper presented at the American Economic Association Annual Meeting, New Orleans, January.

-----. 2002. Rethinking the development agenda. Cambridge Journal of Economics 26.3: 393-407. <http://netec.mcc.ac.uk/BibEc/data/oupcambje.html>. Also available at <http://www.eclac.org/noticias/articulos/4/5784/rethinking3.pdf>.

Ollier, M. M. 2003. Argentina: Up a blind alley once again. Bulletin of Latin American Research 22.2: 170-186.

Patomaki, Heikki. 2001. Democratising globalisation: The leverage of the Tobin tax. London and New York: Zed Books.

Pauly, Louis W. 1997. Who elected the bankers? Surveillance and control in the world economy. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

-----. 1999. Good governance and bad policy: The perils of international organization overextension. Review of International Political Economy 6.4: 401-424.

Pettifor, Ann, Liana Cisneros, and Alejandro Olmos Gaona. 2001. It takes two to tango: Creditor co-responsibility for Argentina's crisis--and the need for independent resolution. London: Jubilee Plus.

Rajan, Ramkishen S. 2000. Examining the case for an Asian Monetary Fund. Visiting Researchers Series, 3. Singapore: Institute for Southeast Asian Studies. Available at: <http://www.iseas.edu.sg/vr32000.pdf>.

Rock, David. 2002. Racking Argentina. New Left Review 17: 55-86.

Sader, Emir. 2003. Can the new leaders leave neoliberalism behind? Latin America: Critical year for the left. Le Monde Diplomatique, February.

Schuler, Kurt. 2002. Fixing Argentina. Policy Analysis, No. 445, 16 July.

Soederberg, S. 2002. The new international financial architecture: Emerging markets and imposed leadership. In Socialist register, edited by Leo Panitch and Colin Leys, 175-192. London: Merlin Press.

Stiglitz, Joseph. 1998. More instruments and broader goals: Moving toward the post-Washington consensus. Helsinki: WIDER Annual Lecture. Available at: <http://www.worldbank.org/html/extdr/extme/js-010798/wider.pdf>.

-----. 2002. Globalization and its discontents. New York: W.W. Norton.

Strange, Susan. 1994. States and markets, 2nd ed. London: Pinter.

-----. 1998a. New world of debt. New Left Review 1.230 (July-August): 91-114.

-----. 1998b. Mad money. Manchester: Manchester University Press.

Underhill, Geoffrey R. D. 1997. Private markets and public responsibility in a global system: Conflict and co-operation in transnational banking and securities regulation. In The new world order in international finance, edited by Geoffrey R. D. Underhill, 17-49. London: Macmillan Press.

US Department of Treasury. 2002. Promoting global growth. Statement of Treasury Secretary Paul H. O'Neill at the International Monetary and Financial Committee Meeting Washington, DC. Washington, DC: US Treasury Secretary.

US House of Representatives Committee on Financial Services. 2003. House panel holds hearing on Chile and Singapore trade agreements. Available at: <http://www.house.gov/apps/list/press/ba31_democrats/CSTA0331.html>.

Wade, R., and F. Veneroso. 1998a. The Asian crisis: The high debt model versus the Wall Street-Treasury-IMF complex. New Left Review 228: 3-24.

-----. 1998b. The gathering world slump and the battle over capital controls. New Left Review 231: 13-43.

Washington Post. 2002. IMF scales down "bankruptcy" plan. 2 April.

Weisbrot, Mark, and Dean Baker. 2002. Paying the bills in Brazil: Does the IMF's math add up? Washington, DC: Center for Economic and Policy Research, 25 September. Available at <http://www.cepr.net/Brazil-debt-final.pdf>.

World Bank. 2000. World development report 2000/01: Attacking poverty. New York: Oxford University Press.

-----. 2003. Global development finance. Washington, DC: World Bank.

(1) See, for example, contributions in this volume as well as Dinerstein (2003a, 2003b), Rock (2002), Mussa (2002), Ollier (2003), Carerra and Cotarelo (2003).

(2) This is not to say that there has not been work on the political facets of the Argentine financial debacle. There is, in fact, a large and important body of literature on this subject.

(3) Capital account liberalization refers to the removal of capital controls or any policy instrument that impedes the freedom if exchange controls on capital transactions in the balance of payments. For a brief discussion on capital account liberalization see Damodaran (2000, 162-163).

(4) According to the IMF data, "the largest member of the IMF is the United States, with a quota of SDR [special drawing right] 37,149.3 million, and the smallest member is Palau, with a quota of SDR 3.1 million." See <http://www.imf.org/external/np/exr/facts/quotas.htm>.

(5) See also Patomaki (2001).

(6) See also contributions in this volume.

(7) See, for example, organizations such as: Jubilee 2000, Debt Relief International, AFL-CIO, and the Mercy Foundation.

(8) See, for example, Financial Times (2002b); Washington Post (2002); The Economist (2002, 67).

(9) Moral hazard describes the risk that "the presence of a contract will affect on the behaviour of one or more parties. The classic example is in the insurance industry, where coverage against a loss might increase the risk-taking behaviour of the insured." Available at: <www.investorwords.com/cgi-bin/getword.cgi?3117&moral%20hazard>.